Ludwig Heinrich Edler von Mises
Austrian School |
 |
Birth |
29 September 1881(1881-09-29)
Lemberg, Austria-Hungary (now Lviv, Ukraine) |
Death |
10 October 1973(1973-10-10) (aged 92)
New York City, New York, USA |
Influences |
Menger, Friedrich Nietzsche, Böhm-Bawerk, Brentano, Say, Bastiat, Turgot, Weber |
Influenced |
Hayek, Rothbard, Kirzner, Hoppe, Schumpeter, Friedman, Buchanan, Robbins, Hülsmann, Allais, Lange, Simons, Hicks, Lachmann, Hutt, Rand, Rockwell, Hazlitt, Salerno, Reisman, Bauer, Paul, Anderson, Smith, Raico, Sennholz |
Part of a series on Libertarianism |
Austrian School |
|
Theoretical works
Principles of Economics
Capital and Interest
Human Action
Individualism and Economic Order
Man, Economy, and State
Competition and Entrepreneurship
|
Theory
Austrian business cycle
Bounded rationality
Catallactics
Consequentalism
Creative destruction
Deontology
Economic calculation problem
Free market
Free price system
Free trade
Homestead principle
View of inflation
Marginalism
Market populism
Methodological individualism
Non-aggression principle
Praxeology
Roundaboutness
Spontaneous order
Subjective theory of value
Theory of interest
|
|
|
People
Austrian School economists
Carl Menger
Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
Friedrich von Wieser · Frank Fetter
Ludwig von Mises
Friedrich Hayek
Murray Rothbard · Israel Kirzner · Ludwig Lachmann
Gerald P. O'Driscoll · Mario Rizzo
Peter Boettke · Lawrence H. White
|
|
|
Philosophy portal
Economics portal |
|
Ludwig Heinrich Edler von Mises (German pronunciation: [ˈluːtvɪç fɔn ˈmiːzəs]; September 29, 1881 – October 10, 1973) was an Austrian economist, philosopher, author and classical liberal who had a significant influence on the modern free-market libertarian movement and the Austrian School.
Biography
Early life
Ludwig von Mises was born in the city of Lemberg, in Galicia, Austria-Hungary (now Lviv in Ukraine), to parents Arthur Edler von Mises from a recently ennobled Jewish family involved in building and financing railroads, and Adele von Mises (née Landau), the niece of Dr. Joachim Landau, a Liberal Party deputy to the Austrian Parliament.[1] Arthur was stationed there as a construction engineer with Czernowitz railway company. At the age of twelve Ludwig spoke fluent Yiddish, German, Polish, and French, read Latin, and could understand Ukrainian.[2] Mises had two younger brothers: applied physicist Richard von Mises, a member of the famous Vienna Circle, and later Karl von Mises, who died in infancy from scarlet fever. When Ludwig and Richard were children, his family moved back to their ancestral home of Vienna.
In 1900, he attended the University of Vienna,[3] becoming influenced by the works of Carl Menger. Mises' father died in 1903, and in 1906 Mises was awarded his doctorate from the school of law.
Professional life
In the years from 1904 to 1914, Mises attended lectures given by the prominent Austrian economist Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk. There, he developed friendships not only with Menger and Böhm-Bawerk, but also prominent sociologist Max Weber.[4] Mises taught as a Privatdozent at the Vienna University in the years from 1913 to 1934 while formally serving as secretary at the Vienna Chamber of Commerce from 1909 to 1934. In these roles, he became one of the closest economic advisers of Engelbert Dollfuss,[5] and, later, Otto von Habsburg.[6] Friends and students of Mises in Europe included Wilhelm Röpke and Alfred Müller-Armack (influential advisors to German chancellor Ludwig Erhard), Jacques Rueff (monetary advisor to Charles de Gaulle), Lord Lionel Robbins (of the London School of Economics), and President of Italy, Luigi Einaudi.[7]
Economist and political theorist F. A. Hayek first came to know Mises while working as Mises' subordinate at a government office dealing with Austria's post-World War I debt. Hayek wrote, "there I came to know him mainly as a tremendously efficient executive, the kind of man who, as was said of John Stuart Mill, because he does a normal day's work in two hours, always has a clear desk and time to talk about anything. I came to know him as one of the best educated and informed men I have ever known..."[8] It was Hayek's development of Mises' innovative theoretical work on the business cycle which later earned him the Nobel Prize in economics.[9]
In 1934, Mises left Austria for Geneva, Switzerland, where he was a professor at the Graduate Institute of International Studies until 1940. Fearing the prospect of Germany taking control over Switzerland, in 1940 Mises with other Jewish refugees left Europe and emigrated to New York City.[10] There he became a visiting professor at New York University, from 1945 until his retirement in 1969, though he was not salaried by the university. Instead, he earned his living from funding by businessmen such as Lawrence Fertig. For part of this period, Mises worked on currency issues for the Pan-Europa movement led by a fellow NYU faculty member and Austrian exile, Richard Coudenhove-Kalergi.[11] In 1947, Mises became one of the founding members of the Mont Pelerin Society.
In America, Mises' work first influenced that of economists such as Benjamin Anderson, Leonard Read and Henry Hazlitt, but also writers such as former radical Max Eastman, who threw a party for Mises in order to celebrate the publication of his treatise Human Action. In addition, novelist Ayn Rand was among those who attended his New York City seminar. His American students included Israel Kirzner, Hans Sennholz, Ralph Raico, Leonard Liggio, George Reisman and Murray Rothbard.[12] Mises later received an honorary doctorate from Grove City College.
Despite his growing fame, Mises listed himself plainly in the New York phone directory and welcomed students into his home.[13] He retired from teaching at the age of 87, then, the oldest active professor in America.[14] Mises died at the age of 92 at St. Vincent's hospital in New York.
Contributions to the field of economics
Part of a series on |
Libertarianism |
|
Theory and ideals
Counter-economics
Dispute resolution organization
Economic freedom
Egalitarianism
Free market
Free society · Free trade
Free will · Freedom of association
Freedom of contract
Homestead principle
Individualism
Laissez-faire
Liberty · Limited government
Methodological individualism
Natural rights
Night watchman state
Non-aggression
Non-interventionism
Non-politics · Non-voting
Participatory economics
Polycentric law · Property
Private defense agency
Self-governance · Self-ownership
Spontaneous order
Stateless society
Subjective theory of value · Tax resistance
Title-transfer theory of contract
Worker's self management
Voluntary association
Voluntary society
|
Schools
Agorism · Anarcho-capitalism
Anarcho-communism · Autarchism
Christian · Consequentalist
Conservative · Constitutionalist
Crypto-anarchism · Deontological
Free market · Geolibertarianism
Green · Left-wing · Marxist
Minarchist · Mutualist
Paleolibertarianism · Panarchist
Propertarianism · Right-wing
Socialist · Voluntaryism
|
|
Related topics
Anti-state · Anti-war
Anarcho-syndicalism
Civil libertarianism
Civil societarianism
Constitutionalism
Free-market environmentalism
Fusionism
Green libertarianism
Libertarian Democrat
Libertarian Republican
Libertarian transhumanism
Market liberalism
Objectivism
Small government
|
|
Libertarianism portal
Liberalism portal
Philosophy portal
Politics portal |
|
Mises wrote and lectured extensively on behalf of classical liberalism and is seen as one of the leaders of the Austrian School of economics.[15] In his treatise on economics, Human Action, Mises introduced praxeology as a more general conceptual foundation of the social sciences and established that economic laws were only arrived at through the means of methodological individualism firmly rejecting positivism and materialism as a foundation for the social sciences. Many of his works, including Human Action, were on two related economic themes:
- monetary economics and inflation;
- the differences between government controlled economies and free trade.
Mises in his library
Mises argued that money is demanded for its usefulness in purchasing other goods, rather than for its own sake and that any unsound credit expansion causes business cycles. His other notable contribution was his argument that socialism must fail economically because of the economic calculation problem – the impossibility of a socialist government being able to make the economic calculations required to organize a complex economy. Mises projected that without a market economy there would be no functional price system, which he held essential for achieving rational and efficient allocation of capital goods to their most productive uses. If capital goods were the subject of neither rent nor exchange as per private ownership of those means of production then no barter terms or money prices could arise for them and without the common nominal index of money pricing that allows comparison of costs of production to likely revenues there could be no rational allocation of diverse capital goods in the production of diverse consumer goods whose production requires some use of scarce capital which in a Socialist society would not be distributed according to the more efficient thus profitable capital structures but to any use a theoretical Socialist planner would see fit without the aid of monetary price signals to compare the profitability in a given use of capital. Socialism would fail as demand cannot be known without prices, according to Mises, therefore Socialist waste of capital goods would be as chronic as the incentives for production and retention of capital would be low while they were coercively monopolised by a dysfunctional State operating with only the data pertaining to interpersonal comparisons of utility as per democratic production, which is not sufficient for economic calculation and therefore neither for efficient use and allocation of capital whose place in a free market is ordained by the prices set by private owners of the means of production who keep capital where its production is remunerated best by consumers and who liquidate it and pass it to other uses if production is bankrupt. In Socialism such means for liquidation of capital goods and the passage or maintenance of the means of production across extremely diverse applications throughout the divisions of labour according to the expense or cheapness of bidding capital away from vital production, would simply not be present. Mises' criticism of socialist paths of economic development is well-known, such as in his 1922 work Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis:
The only certain fact about Russian affairs under the Soviet regime with regard to which all people agree is: that the standard of living of the Russian masses is much lower than that of the masses in the country which is universally considered as the paragon of capitalism, the United States of America. If we were to regard the Soviet regime as an experiment, we would have to say that the experiment has clearly demonstrated the superiority of capitalism and the inferiority of socialism.[16]
These arguments were elaborated on by subsequent Austrian economists such as Nobel laureate Friedrich Hayek[17] and students such as Hans Sennholz.
In Interventionism, An Economic Analysis (1940), Ludwig von Mises wrote:
The usual terminology of political language is stupid. What is 'left' and what is 'right'? Why should Hitler be 'right' and Stalin, his temporary friend, be 'left'? Who is 'reactionary' and who is 'progressive'? Reaction against an unwise policy is not to be condemned. And progress towards chaos is not to be commended. Nothing should find acceptance just because it is new, radical, and fashionable. 'Orthodoxy' is not an evil if the doctrine on which the 'orthodox' stand is sound. Who is anti-labor, those who want to lower labor to the Russian level, or those who want for labor the capitalistic standard of the United States? Who is 'nationalist,' those who want to bring their nation under the heel of the Nazis, or those who want to preserve its independence?
Robert Heilbroner opined after the fall of the Soviet Union, that "It turns out, of course, that Mises was right" about the impossibility of socialism. "Capitalism has been as unmistakable a success as socialism has been a failure. Here is the part that's hard to swallow. It has been the Friedmans, Hayeks, and von Miseses who have maintained that capitalism would flourish and that socialism would develop incurable ailments."[18]
Mises developed the theory of the 'sovereignty of the consumer' in a free-market economy; in his view, the consumer ultimately dictates everything that happens. This argument is set out in a memorable passage in 'Human Action':
'The captain is the consumer…the consumers determine precisely what should be produced, in what quality, and in what quantities…They are merciless egoistic bosses, full of whims and fancies, changeable and unpredictable. For them nothing counts other than their own satisfaction…In their capacity as buyers and consumers they are hard-hearted and callous, without consideration for other people…Capitalists…can only preserve and increase their wealth by filling best the orders of the consumers… In the conduct of their business affairs they must be unfeeling and stony-hearted because the consumers, their bosses, are themselves unfeeling and stony-hearted.’[19]
The context does not suggest that Mises is trying here to denigrate the consumer society. On the contrary, he is describing the free-market economy as he believes that it naturally is and should be.
Criticism
Milton Friedman considered Mises intolerant in his personal behavior:
The story I remember best happened at the initial Mont Pelerin meeting when he got up and said, "You're all a bunch of socialists." We were discussing the distribution of income, and whether you should have progressive income taxes. Some of the people there were expressing the view that there could be a justification for it.
Another occasion which is equally telling: Fritz Machlup was a student of Mises's, one of his most faithful disciples. At one of the Mont Pelerin meetings, Fritz gave a talk in which I think he questioned the idea of a gold standard; he came out in favor of floating exchange rates. Mises was so mad he wouldn't speak to him for three years. Some people had to come around and bring them together again. It's hard to understand; you can get some understanding of it by taking into account how people like Mises were persecuted in their lives.[20]
In a 1957 review of his book, The Anti-Capitalistic Mentality, The Economist said of von Mises: "Professor von Mises has a splendid analytical mind and an admirable passion for liberty; but as a student of human nature he is worse than null and as a debater he is of Hyde Park standard."[21]
In a 1978 interview Friedrich Hayek said about his book Socialism: "At first we all felt he was frightfully exaggerating and even offensive in tone. You see, he hurt all our deepest feelings, but gradually he won us around, although for a long time I had to -- I just learned he was usually right in his conclusions, but I was not completely satisfied with his argument."[22]
Famous Quotes
"There is no means of avoiding the final collapse of a boom brought about by credit expansion. The alternative is only whether the crisis should come sooner as a result of a voluntary abandonment of further credit expansion, or later as a final total catastrophe of the currency involved."
"If they do not plan new aggressions, they are not in need of arms."
"It is perfectly legitimate to assume that the races are different in their cognitive abilities and in their willpower and accordingly are unequally suited for the task of setting up societies, and that the better races are characterized in particular by their special ability to strengthen social bonds."
"The masses do not think. This is precisely the reason why they follow those who do think. The intellectual leadership of mankind is a position held by the very few who are able to think."
"A man who chooses between drinking a glass of milk and a glass of a solution of potassium cyanide does not choose between two beverages; he chooses between life and death. A society that chooses between capitalism and socialism does not choose between two social systems; it chooses between social cooperation and the disintegration of society. Socialism is not an alternative to capitalism; it is an alternative to any system under which men can live as human beings."
"Fascism can triumph today because universal indignation at the infamies committed by the socialists and communists has obtained for it the sympathies of wide circles. But when the fresh impression of the crimes of the Bolsheviks has paled, the socialist programm will once again exercise its power of attraction on the masses. For Fascism does nothing to combat it except to suppress socialist ideas and to persecute the people who spread them. If it wanted to really combat socialism, it would have to oppose it with ideas. There is, however, only one [emphasis in original] idea that can be effectively opposed to socialism, viz., that of liberalism" It cannot be denied that Fascism and similar movements aiming at the establishment of dictatorships are full of the best intentions and that their intervention has, for the moment, saved European civilization. The merit that Fascism has thereby won for itself will live on eternally in history. But though its policy has brought salvation for the moment, it is not of the kind which could promise continued success. Fascism was an emergency makeshift. To view it as something more would be a fatal error."
(to Ayn Rand) "But Atlas Shrugged is not merely a novel. It is also (or may I say: first of all) a cogent analysis of the evils that plague our society, a substantiated rejection of the ideology of our self-styled "intellectuals" and a pitiless unmasking of the insincerity of the policies adopted by governments and political parties. It is a devastating exposure of the "moral cannibals," the "gigolos of science" and of the "academic prattle" of the makers of the "anti-industrial revolution." You have the courage to tell the masses what no politician told them: you are inferior and all the improvements in your conditions which you simply take for granted you owe to the efforts of men who are better than you."
Bibliography
- The Theory of Money and Credit (1912, enlarged US edition 1953)
- Nation, State, and Economy (1919)
- Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis (1922, 1932, 1951)
- Liberalism (1927, 1962)
- A Critique of Interventionism (1929)
- Epistemological Problems of Economics (1933, 1960)
- Memoirs (1940)
- Interventionism: An Economic Analysis (1941, 1998)
- Omnipotent Government: The Rise of Total State and Total War (1944)
- Bureaucracy (1944, 1962)
- Planned Chaos (1947, added to 1951 edition of Socialism)
- Human Action: A Treatise on Economics (1949, 1963, 1966, 1996)
- Planning for Freedom (1952, enlarged editions in 1962, 1974, and 1980)
- The Anti-Capitalistic Mentality (1956)
- Theory and History: An Interpretation of Social and Economic Evolution (1957)
- The Ultimate Foundation of Economic Science (1962)
- The Historical Setting of the Austrian School of Economics (1969)
- Notes and Recollections (1978)
- The Clash of Group Interests and Other Essays (1978)
- On the Manipulation of Money and Credit (1978)
- Economic Policy: Thoughts for Today and Tomorrow (1979, lectures given in 1959)
- Money, Method, and the Market Process (1990)
- Economic Freedom and Interventionism (1990)
- The Free Market and Its Enemies (2004, lectures given in 1951)
- Marxism Unmasked: From Delusion to Destruction (2006, lectures given in 1952)
- Ludwig von Mises on Money and Inflation (2010, lectures given in the 1960s)
Selected books by Ludwig von Mises |
|
The Theory of Money and Credit (1912) • Socialism (1922) • Liberalism (1927) • Omnipotent Government (1944) • Bureaucracy (1944) • Human Action (1949) • The Anti-Capitalistic Mentality (1956)
|
|
See also
- Analytic-synthetic distinction and Ludwig von Mises' response to the Kantian challenge
- Contributions to liberal theory
- Liberalism in Austria
- Libertarianism
- List of Austrian scientists
- List of Austrians
- Mont Pelerin Society
- Karl Polanyi - with whom von Mises debated leading to Polanyi's book The Great Transformation
- Lew Rockwell founder of Ludwig von Mises Institute
- Murray Rothbard important disciple of von Mises
- Ludwig von Mises Institute
- Gitta Sereny His stepdaughter
Further reading
- Eamonn Butler. Ludwig von Mises - A Primer, Institute of Economic Affairs (2010)
- Brian Doherty. Radicals for Capitalism: A Freewheeling History of the Modern American Libertarian Movement (2007)
- "A Tribute to Ludwig Von Mises". A list of works by and on Ludwig Von Mises by the Foundation for Economic Education.
- Jörg Guido Hülsmann. Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism (Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2007), xvi+1143 pages, ISBN 978-1-933550-18-3. Also available as a PDF file.
- Ron Paul. "Mises and Austrian economics: A personal view" The Ludwig von Mises Institute of Auburn University (1984), 31 pages.
- Murray N. Rothbard (1987). "Mises. Ludwig Edler von," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 3, pp. 479–80.
Notes
- Note regarding personal names: Edler is a title, (<G, meaning 'noble'), in rank similar to that of a baronet, not a first or middle name. The female form is Edle. Similarly, below, Ritter is German for 'knight'; Graf is German for 'count'.
- ↑ Hulsmann, Jörg Guido (2007). Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism. Ludwig von Mises Institute. pp. 3–9.
- ↑ Erik Ritter von Kuehnelt-Leddihn "The Cultural Background of Ludwig von Mises", The Ludwig von Mises Institute, page 1
- ↑ Von Mises, Ludwig; Goddard, Arthur (1979). Liberalism: a socio-economic exposition (2 ed.). ISBN 0836251067.
- ↑ Mises, Ludwig von, The Historical Setting of the Austrian School of Economics, Arlington Houise, 1969, reprinted by the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1984, p. 10, Rothbard, Murray, The Essential Ludwig von Mises, 2nd printing, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1983, p. 30.
- ↑ "The Free Market: Meaning of the Mises Papers, The". Mises.org. http://mises.org/freemarket_detail.aspx?control=137. Retrieved 2009-11-26.
- ↑ Mises, Margit von, My Years with Ludwig von Mises, Arlington House, 1976, 2nd enlarged edit., Center for Future Education, 1984.
- ↑ Rothbard, Murray, Ludwig von Mises: Scholar, Creator, Hero, the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1988, p. 67.
- ↑ Mises, Margit von, My Years with Ludwig von Mises, Arlington House, 1976, 2nd enlarged edit., Center for Future Education, 1984, pp. 219-220.
- ↑ Rothbard, Murray, Ludwig von Mises: Scholar, Creator, Hero, the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1988, p. 68.
- ↑ Hulsmann, Jorg Guido (2007). Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism. Ludwig von Mises Institute. p. xi.
- ↑ Coudenhove-Kalergi, Richard Nikolaus, Graf von (1953). An idea conquers the world. London: Hutchinson. p. 247.
- ↑ On Mises' influence, see Rothbard, Murray, The Essential Ludwig von Mises, 2nd printing, the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1983; on Eastman's conversion "from Marx to Mises," see Diggins, John P., Up From Communism Harper & Row, 1975, pp. 201-233; on Mises's students and seminar attendees, see Mises, Margit von, My Years with Ludwig von Mises, Arlington House, 1976, 2nd enlarged edit., Center for Future Education, 1984.
- ↑ Reisman, George, Capitalism: a Treatise on Economics, "Introduction," Jameson Books, 1996; and Mises, Margit von, My Years with Ludwig von Mises, 2nd enlarged edit., Center for Future Education, 1984, pp. 136-137.
- ↑ Rothbard, Murray, Ludwig von Mises: Scholar, Creator, Hero, the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1988, p.61.
- ↑ For example, Murray Rothbard, a leading Austrian school economist, has written that, by the 1920s, "Mises was clearly the outstanding bearer of the great Austrian tradition." Ludwig von Mises: Scholar, Creator, Hero, the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1988, p. 25.
- ↑ Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis by Ludwig von Mises.
- ↑ F. A. Hayek, (1935), "The Nature and History of the Problem" and "The Present State of the Debate," in F. A. Hayek, ed. Collectivist Economic Planning, pp. 1-40, 201-43.
- ↑ Reason.com, "The Man Who Told the Truth" Reason, 1990. Retrieved on April 4, 2009.
- ↑ 'Human Action' chap. 15, sect. 4
- ↑ "Best of Both Worlds (Interview with Milton Friedman)". Reason. June 1995. http://www.reason.com/news/show/29691.html.
- ↑ "Liberalism in Caricature", The Economist
- ↑ UCLA Oral History (Interview with Friedrich Hayek), American Libraries/Internet Archive, 1978. Retrieved on April 4, 2009 (Blog.Mises.org), source with quotes
External links
- Mises.org, Ludwig von Mises Institute
- Mises.org, The Complete Mises Bibliography from the Ludwig von Mises Institute
- Mises.org, Biography from the Ludwig von Mises Institute
- Mises.org, Biography by Mises scholar Jörg Guido Hülsmann
- Mises.org, Mises on Keynes 1927 review by Mises on a lecture given by Keynes in Berlin
- Mises.de, Books and Articles in the original German versions by Ludwig von Mises and other Authors of the Austrian School]
- YouTube.com, The Life and Work of Ludwig von Mises Jörg Guido Hülsmann
- Ludwig von Mises at the Open Directory Project
- Biblioteca.ufm.edu n Biblioteca Ludwig von Mises
- Lewrockwell.com, Scholar, Creator, Hero, Murray Rothbard on Mises
- LibertyFund.org, Nine Books by Mises, made available online by the Liberty Fund publishers of the Complete Works of Ludwig von Mises
- My Years With Ludwig von Mises by Margit von Mises. 1976. Memoir of their life together.
Austrian School economists |
|
Founders |
|
|
Public figures |
|
|
Austrian School influences |
|
|
Austrian macroeconomics |
Benjamin Anderson • Frank Fetter • Roger Garrison • Gottfried Haberler • Steven Horwitz • Jesús Huerta de Soto • Ludwig Lachmann • George Selgin • Hans Sennholz • Mark Skousen • Lawrence White
|
|
Austrian microeconomics |
Walter Block • Gene Callahan • Randall Holcombe • Israel Kirzner • Peter Leeson • Fritz Machlup • Robert P. Murphy
|
|
Austrian history and methodology |
Peter Boettke • Bruce Caldwell • Thomas DiLorenzo • Richard Ebeling • Robert Higgs • Hans-Hermann Hoppe • Lionel Robbins • Murray N. Rothbard • Joseph T. Salerno
|
|
Schools of economic thought |
|
Pre-modern |
|
|
Early modern |
|
|
Modern |
Classical · French liberal · American (National) · German historical · English historical · French historical · Utopian · Marxian · State socialism · Ricardian · Ricardian socialism · Christian socialism · Distributism · Anarchist · Georgism · Neoclassical · Lausanne
|
|
20th century |
Stockholm · Keynesian · New classical · Chicago · Austrian · Carnegie · Neo-Ricardian · New institutional · Post-Keynesian · Islamic · Gandhian · Institutional · Freiburg · Social Credit
|
|
Related |
|
|
Persondata |
Name |
Mises, Ludwig von |
Alternative names |
|
Short description |
|
Date of birth |
September 29, 1881 |
Place of birth |
|
Date of death |
October 10, 1973 |
Place of death |
|
|